Preview of Review of 'Happiness and Economic Growth'

Happiness and Economic Growth: Lessons from developing countries, by Andrew E. Clark and Claudia Senik eds. (Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK,  2014) pp. xiv + 277



This book is a great way to get across what’s cutting edge in economic research into happiness. The contributions are all World Class and come from prominent scholars in both the academy and relevant organisations like the OECD and World Bank. Each chapter is well written with clearly articulated take away points. However, there is very little in here that is really new. Rather, most of Happiness and Economic Growth provides finer gradations on things we already know.

The fundamental question this book sets out to investigate is whether income growth makes people happier. The standard answer to this question is that income growth does make people happier but that this positive relationship suffers from rather severe diminishing returns. Up until middle income status there is a strong positive relationship after which the marginal returns curve starts to flatten rapidly.

The classic explanations for this phenomenon—the so-called ‘Easterlin Paradox’—are adaptation, reference group effects, rescaling and the opportunity cost of income, notably more hours at work. While the present volume rarely strays from these well-worn paths it provides a lot of new details gleamed from powerful Chinese data.

China is a fascinating case study for these questions because of its large, rapid growth in recent decades, increasing inequality, the stark divide between rural and urban development and the presence of large groups of easily identifiable internal migrants. Happiness and Economic Growth does an excellent job of collecting the lessons we can learn about happiness and development from studying China’s growth miracle.

One of the most interesting collections of findings concerns the interplay between happiness and dramatic structural change. Easterlin’s chapter is particularly striking in this regard. It identifies a u-shape in the happiness of citizens in China between 1990 and 2010. This, he suggests, is explained by substantial unemployment during the initial transition from state-led development wherein employment was guaranteed (indeed compulsory) to market-led development wherein many people became unexpectedly unemployed.

There is also the suggestion elsewhere in the volume that people dislike the insecurity rapid change brings about, and this may offset the positive effects of income growth on happiness. Other commentators note the role entrenched positive expectations generated by sustained high growth rates play in boosting people’s present happiness.

One tension that runs through the book is between some contributors who emphasise the relevance of the findings to public policy and those who advise caution. For example, Easterlin says in his chapter that:
“The present results demonstrate the value of subjective well-being measures such as happiness or life satisfaction as a guide to policy. Output measures lead one to focus on firms and their productivity, while happiness measures lead directly to the lives and personal concerns of individuals and bring out possible costs in terms of human suffering that are missed by GDP.” (pg. 20)
Martin Ravallion is the most prominent antagonist to this view in the text. He repeatedly emphasises the possibility that people are changing their scales over the course of development, which would make these happiness comparisons across time and place largely meaningless, if not dangerous:
“Economic development is a process of structural change, which changes people’s reference groups and scales. It changes how you think of the world where you live when you move from a village, where the reference group is very narrow, to a city with a very vast set of people at different levels of living. In that process, the scale of subjective well-being that we use is surely going to change.” (pg. 246)
To get a sense for why this discussion is important we might employ the following sanity check. The results discussed in Easterlin’s chapter would seem to imply that people were happier in China in the immediate aftermath of the events of June 1989 (the incidents of Tiananmen Square, which were mirrored nation-wide) than during the extensive market liberalisation of the subsequent Zemin & Rongji years, or even the reactionary years of sustained high growth but relatively limited structural change under Jintao & Jiaobao (Overholt 2015). Observers of China’s history, literature and popular culture may well consider such a proposition unlikely.

Read the rest of the article at: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/1475-4932.12251/abstract

Comments