You know how people sometimes cut down their 3rd year
politics essay and submit it for publication in Woroni? Well today I’m doing
just that (only this is my blog, not Woroni). We did the carbon tax in class a few weeks ago and I want to write
about it, mostly because it is surprisingly simple, and makes for a nice horse
to flog about the inadequacies of our public discourse.
Our society is going
to have a very hard time managing the increasingly complex policy issues of
contemporary society if our media can’t (or won’t?) communicate an idea of this
complexity to the public, at least to the educated public.
A great many people argue that the carbon tax is a pointless
policy because the compensation it incorporates means that nobody will actually
shift their consumption away from carbon. This is wrong. Allow me to explain
using my newfound economics skills. I will use a graph first, which might be a
bit complex. I will then use a hypothetical example.
Figure 1 shows an individual’s consumption between two
categories of goods—carbon intensive goods (the x-axis) and carbon-neutral
goods (the y-axis). It shows the effect of an increase in the price of carbon
intensive goods, as you would get under a carbon tax.
The curves marked U1 & U2 represent
different levels of utility derived from
the same set of preferences. That is to say, throughout this exercise, the
preferences of the individual do not change; that is why the U curves are
identical, U1 is just higher than U2. It is higher
because at the original price of carbon (PX1) the individual can
afford more of both goods than at PX2, and this gives them a higher
level of utility. As you move towards the north-east corner of the graph you
move towards higher (better) levels of utility.
The red lines represent the individual’s budget
constraints—their income. Under the original conditions the individual consumes
at point A. Here, the individual’s utility function touches their budget
constraint. Point A is an optimum point because it is the highest point on the
U1 curve that can be reached within the budget constraint.
After the carbon tax, the price of carbon increases, so the consumer can
now afford less carbon intensive goods. This is represented by the budget
constraint shrinking away from the x-axis to PX2. The individuals
‘real income’ is now lower. Their nominal income has not changed, but it can
afford less of the goods in question.
At this level of income, the individual can no longer
reach U1, so the individual attains a lower level of utility—U2.
This optimisation process on the part of the individual is captured in point B,
which is the point at which U2 can be reached with the least
expenditure.
Notice that at B the individual is consuming less carbon
intensive goods than at point A. Win if your objective is to move people away
from carbon. However, the individual is also worse off because they are at a
lower level of utility. So the government compensates
them with money to get them back to their original level of utility, U1.
But note that the compensation moves their consumption to
point C, not back to A. Why? Because prices have changed! Under the new price
regime the individual’s budget constraint is captured by the lime line (the
‘substitution effect’, which shows the impact of a price change while holding
real income constant). Notice that the lime line has the same slope as the
budget constraint at B.
Under this price regime and budget constraint the point
where the individual can reach U1 is no longer A, but C. Note that C involves less carbon consumption
than A. This is so because prices have changed and individuals are
rational—they will optimise away from relatively expensive goods.
Let’s try and relate all this complex graphical analysis
to a real world example. Consider an individual, Bob, who can tick the ‘I want
to use green energy sources’ box on his electricity bill for a price of $20.
Bob is frugal and is thus disinclined to tick the box. Prior to the carbon tax
his bill is $50 and he gets all the power he needs. After the tax his bill is
$70 dollars either way. Bob seems worse off, except that the government gives
him $20 dollars to cover the expense of the carbon tax. Unless Bob is heartless
he is going to tick the green energy box, because it now makes no difference to
him regardless. The compensation has not driven down the cost of carbon, so now
green energy is price competitive, and Bob will choose it. Bob is exactly where
he was before in terms of utility, but the world has a little less carbon in it
(and the government lost money).
Some observant readers may have noticed that this
hypothetical example (and graph) is not entirely accurate, because point C typically involves more
carbon consumption than B. An uncompensated carbon tax would get the job
done better than a compensated one, but it also leaves people worse off.
Government compensation is expensive, as is a carbon tax in the first place,
due to its adverse effects on economic activity. There is thus certainly an
argument to be made that compensation mitigates the effectiveness of the
anti-carbon policy, and an even better argument (though unconvincing in my
opinion) to be made that it is prohibitively expensive. But to say that it
makes the policy pointless is fallacious.
There are two counterarguments worth analysing. The first
is that the above is all good and well at the level of consumers, but that
Australia’s carbon tax compensates polluters. As I understand the carbon tax,
this is incorrect. The government does not compensate polluters in a manner
that allows them to continue ‘business as usual’. Firms can request funding to
‘clean-up’ or ‘green-up’ their operations. They don’t get money to just keep
doing what they’ve been doing. That would indeed be a totally stupid policy.
The second counter argues that clean industry,
particularly with regards to energy, does not have the capacity at present to
handle all the new business generated by the tax. But this is a touch banal,
because a key selling point of the tax is that it will encourage clean energy
to build capacity. Under the new price regime clean industry is price
competitive with dirty industry, which encourages consumers to purchase its
goods. Firms respond to this demand by increasing supply. There may be some lag
in the short run, but in a highly competitive and elastic economy like
Australia that lag is minimal. This is especially the case given the long lead-in
time for the carbon tax, wherein firms could position themselves to capitalise
on the price regime as soon as it hit. I could explain this dynamic transition
with the static model above, but it would be slow and clunky, so I won’t
bother.
The line of reasoning pursued in this piece strikes me as
reasonably easy to follow. I have left out the maths, but even that is not
particularly difficult. Anyone who has done advanced maths in year 12 should be
able to follow (there’s a bit of differentiation, that’s all). In this context
it strikes me as bizarre that I have not come across such an explanation of the
carbon tax outside of class. What is our media doing? The course I’m doing is
the equivalent of microeconomics three for undergraduates. We expect our public
intellectuals to be able to effectively explain third year political science
concepts to us (like multiculturalism or feminism), so we should also expect
them to be able to explain third year economics concepts to us. I recall Ross
Garnaut expressing anger with the media’s analysis of the tax at the time of
its implementation, but I had no idea it was this bad.
Comments
Post a Comment