The government has found some gold in its reforms to
higher education, but lost the plot along the way. An extension of income
contingent loans to TAFE and other vocational qualifications is a smart move.
Forcing PhD students to pay fees is not. Reforming fee structures was necessary,
but has been cocked up.
One reasonable
solution proposed by the Group of Eight was to move to the postgraduate system
across the board. In this case, universities respond to market demand for a
certain quality-cost balance and set appropriate fees and quality to maximise
revenue and other outcomes like international prestige. Postgraduate degrees
typically cost around $25000 and you get what you pay for. Students consider
the cost and quality and decide whether they want to buy. They can then apply
for an income contingent loan from the government for the full value of the
degree. The government pays this to the university and then collects the debt
from the student. The university knows exactly how much it is getting per
student, so it can ensure quality is commensurate to demand, and that the cost
of delivery is met.
The main problem with this proposal is the difficulty
of retaining a demand driven model for public funding. Some decent suggestions
include block grants for teaching based on student enrolment numbers and block
grants for research based on research output, research staff numbers or some
other criteria that ensures some universities specialise in high end teaching
and research, and others in low-end teaching or specific kinds of research
(e.g. into agriculture at rural universities).
The new system post-budget is something else
entirely. Essentially, everything is the same as before, but now universities
can make the sticker price of a degree whatever they want.
This system has three key problems. First, there is
a still a government subsidy incorporated into the sticker price. This means
the universities are still unsure of how much money they get per student. Economic
theory tells us that they are thus likely to overcharge to ensure they don’t
incur a loss. But in the context of a budget emergency, the government may
respond by dropping funding to zero on the grounds that the universities are now
making all they need from fees. This is a bad situation. Fees go up but there
is no guarantee that quality will match, and public funding for universities
evaporates.
Second, income-contingent loans now come with a real
rate of interest. This is a silly policy. The government hopes to make some
revenue by charging interest on student debt. But what’s just as likely to
happen is that the interest will encourage more people to elope overseas with
debts and simply never pay them off.
Importantly, the equity of our higher education
financing system depends heavily on there being no real rate of interest on income
contingent loans. Free education is a regressive policy. It results in the
taxes of the poor going to subsidise the rich to get richer. It is also fiscally
unsustainable in the face of current demand—that’s why a Labor government
introduced HECS in the first place. Income contingent loans have been shown
empirically to maintain the enrolment rates of disadvantaged individuals while
alleviating the financial burden of publically providing higher education. But
real interest rates muddy the waters. Wealthy individuals able to pay up front
now essentially get cheaper degrees than those who must pay later. Individuals
with debt burdens will also be forced to pay them off faster, which will
discourage them from partaking in low-paid internships in the early part of
their careers. Yet many of the most lucrative jobs require such internships.
The government gets its money back a little sooner, but at a cost to social
mobility.
Third is the decision to charge PhDs fees. This will
discourage international talent from attending Australian universities,
exacerbate the brain drain and deter many students from postgraduate study
entirely. It will deprive universities of quality research assistants and
tutors and industry of highly trained staff. In many disciplines, PhDs are a
crucial professional requirement. For example, much high end scientific
equipment cannot be operated without a PhD spent learning the machinery.
Statistical techniques in high demand in business are learnt predominantly in
postgraduate courses. Perhaps more importantly, PhD students are currently paid
less than an apprentice on a union construction site. The decision for someone
with a master’s degree and huge earning potential to pursue further study is
thus already an enormous financial sacrifice. Why make it even more
difficult?
A final bone of contention in these reforms is the
potential explosion in the cost of a university degree. The jury is still out
on whether this will occur, though treasury modelling suggests it is likely.
Undergraduate courses are fundamentally cheaper to deliver than postgraduate
ones, so we are unlikely to see costs like those associated with postgraduate
degrees in Australia. However, the Group of Eight has expressed a desire to
compete with top international universities, many of which charge in excess of
$25000, so we will have to wait and see.
The fact remains though that these costs will not
make degrees a bad investment. The net present value of university degrees is
still many times the cost of acquiring one. Income contingent loans make these
costs manageable even for those with no initial capital. There are valid concerns
that an income contingent debt burden of $30000 is fundamentally different to a
debt burden of $120000, but we won’t know the effects for some time because
other countries with high student debt burdens don’t have income contingent
loan systems the way we do.
The government tried to do some good things in the
most recent round of higher education reforms, the extension of HECS to TAFE is
particular praiseworthy, but on balance, they botched it. A desire to respond
to analysis from commentators like the Grattan institute and advocacy from
higher education providers was muddled by an obsession with balancing the
books. There’s a good chance we’ll all be worse off for it.
Comments
Post a Comment