Former Australian Treasurer Wayne Swan recently delivered a
speech at the Australian workers’ union national conference that has attracted
a fair bit of commentary. You can find a full transcript here: https://swanmp.org/news-media/speeches/speech-restoring-class-balance-bargaining-power-and-full-employment-in-the-21st-century/.
I broadly agree with the thrust of the speech, but some of the technical
details struck me as quite wrong and indicative of deep misunderstandings among
the left (though everyone is muddled on this stuff, including if not
especially, the right) regarding what needs addressing in contemporary economic
trends. The below is basically an endorsement of the political message of the speech
and a bunch of caveats about the technical analysis in it.
First, a quick list of some of the things in the speech that
I think were bang on. First, the notion of wage-led growth is something I
wholeheartedly endorse. Obviously, investment is a critical headline figure,
but jobless investment is pretty pointless from a welfare enhancing and/or
Rawlsian point of view, and wage growth drives broad-based consumption growth, which
is critical for economic development that is felt by society broadly. If you
care about healthy communities then you care about wage growth, not GDP growth.
Second, greater accountability on capital and the corporate
sector seems a no-brainer, especially as far as competition policy is
concerned. I’m quite fond of capitalists, but they should be exposed to
competition like anybody else, and we are increasingly struggling in Australia
on that front. Andrew Leigh and my PhD colleague Adam Triggs have done some
great work on this recently. Check it out in pop
form here and academic
form here.
Tax reform to ‘defend and advance our world-leading
progressive tax system’ is something I can get behind, especially viz. the
Henry tax review, Leigh’s work on corporate tax, and policies to encourage sensible
long-term investment decisions on the part of firms rather than riskier
short-term profit maximising behaviour.
As I said, I broadly agree with the thrust of the speech
that it is critical that Australia remains a worker’s paradise and an exemplary
‘market-disciplined welfare-state’, which is what I think we are—the best in
the world. (Note though, that we are a workers paradise because we always have good jobs going, not because we privilege labour over capital. France does the latter and it is not a workers' paradise because unemployment is rampant and huge numbers of outsiders can only find irregular work).
That said, there were some points in the speech that I
thought were dumb and troubling insofar as they suggest the labour movement is
pretty far behind the times.
First, the discussion of underemployment is a red herring,
one that the left seems to be fixating on a lot at the moment. Very few
underemployed people are actually looking for more work. Here’s the data from
the first 12 waves of HILDA to 2012 (the effect got stronger in the next 3 years, but I don't have the data to hand). The graph shows all the people who work less than
30 but more than 0 hours per week. ‘1’ means you want to work less, ‘2’ means
you are happy with your hours, and ‘3’ means you want to work more. More than
half of the people here don’t want to work more, and indeed, a large number
want to work even less. What we need to do is make it easier for people to
match their preferred hours to a job, not just increase the number of full-time
jobs available. This is especially true for parents, see below.
Second, Swan suggests we should target an unemployment rate
of 3%. This is weird given that the RBA and treasury both see the natural rate
of unemployment as 5% these days. The reason for the natural rate rising over
time is the growing causalisation of the workforce and the greater use of
contracts rather than permanent positions. This has resulted in greater churn
in the labour market, with people being between jobs more frequently. As a
result, the headline unemployment rate is higher at any one time, but people
are not spending much time unemployed, so it’s not a bad thing, especially as
they earn more this way. What would be more appropriate to target would be the
long-term unemployed rate, which is rising. It would also be helpful to see
whether they are any notable frictions in the labour market that make it hard
for contract workers to find new jobs. My understanding is that we don’t do a
great job of reducing information shortfalls in the labour market in Australia.
Now of course the labour movement sees contracts and
causalisation as bad things for the most part. This to me seems excessively
black and white. For a start, much of this is driven by women’s greater
participation in the workforce. They need such work arrangements to manage
parenting and work commitments. Causal and contract formats also make it easier
to work less by going freelance and working when you want to. What I would need
to see to convince me that we actually have a problem is some data showing that
many people doing casual and contract labour would prefer permanent contracts and don’t get them even after some
reasonable period of time, say 12 months.
I find the emphasis on full-time, permanent jobs a little
old fashioned and a little weird. It’s old fashioned because it doesn’t reckon
with changing household dynamics (i.e. labour-left have an implicit concept of
a single-breadwinner household) and because it assumes that the kinds of jobs
available these days can be made permanent (and with only minimal cost in terms
of efficiency). It’s a little weird because I would have thought the long-term
goal of the labour movement would be to reduce work hours. So why are they
concerned about people working less and happy about it? I presume it’s just
because they are missing that ‘and happy about it’ part.
Third, while I fully endorse having not just private sector
people on the RBA board, putting Sally McManus on there is absolutely batshit
crazy. It should be a basic requirement of board membership that you think
capital has a marginal product.
Fourth, the constant use of ‘trickle-down economics’ and the
as-always offhand use of ‘neoliberalism’ makes me nauseous. On the former of
these two notions, I direct the reader’s attention to Thomas Sowell’s essay ‘“Trickle-down
theory” and “tax-cuts for the rich”’, available here: http://www.tsowell.com/images/Hoover%20Proof.pdf.
There are two main things to take away from this essay. First, no economist (or
even right-wing politician) ever has endorsed something called ‘trickle-down
economics’. It is a rhetorical invention of the left. Second, the Reagan and
Bush era tax cuts dramatically increased total tax receipts from the rich. This
is because prior to the tax cuts, the wealthy were storing large portions of
their wealth in tax-free, low-interest governments securities. After the tax
cuts, they moved their capital to higher-yielding but also taxed assets because
even with the tax, they made more money this way. So inequality increased, but the wealthy were also paying heaps more tax that could fund transfers.
Now of course, Reagan spent the extra government revenue on bombs and Bush on
war in the middle east, but the point stands that you have a difficult trade
off here between more inequality and more government funds for transfers. If the
money is spent on transfers, you’re basically looking at either a higher gini
coefficient or a higher bottom-decile to top-decile ratio. It strikes me as
difficult to choose between the two within left-wing ethical paradigms, but
personally I’m much more inclined towards more transfer payments (and I’m
Rawlsian, which I’d say it pretty bloody left).
That’s just looking at tax-receipts. There is also the fact
that the rich invested their money in higher yielding assets, which means more
growth and, probably, more jobs. Now I’m not saying that concessions to the
rich are good for growth, but I am saying that concessions to the rich can be good for growth. You need to take
these things on a case by case and see what the data says. I’m of course sceptical
of most complaints on the part of the wealthy that they are being taxed too
much, and I am of course always wary of the power of money and lobbying. But my
concerns either way are going to be influenced by data and not by ideological
rhetoric.
Fifth, concerns about 2% wage growth seem misplaced when GDP
growth is 2%, especially as not all of that growth would be the marginal product
of labour. In this regard, I am constantly struck by the ham-fisted engagement
(if there even is any) with technological change on the part of labour
movements in the rich countries. Information and coordination technologies
(ICT) and automation are buttressing the marginal product of capital such that
capital is not becoming cyclically more expensive than labour the way it did in
the past, hence the greater capital share in growth and flatlining wages.
Certainly, the decline of labour power is a part of this declining wage share,
but it’s also true that the decline in labour power is substantially a function
of exogenous technological change,
not endogenous changing institutional
structures. What’s needed in this context is adaptation on the part of the
labour side of labour market institutions to assist labour in benefitting from
technological change. I am thinking in particular of much more sophisticated
structures for lifelong learning, like what they have in Scandinavia (those
thoroughly market economies that have a strange reputation for being socialist).
Instead, most of the thrust from labour groups seems to be directed at
bargaining platforms (i.e. the French model). This would result in greater
extraction of profits even as labour’s contribution to those profits declines, which
to me seems a politically untenable long-term position, and liable to incite
the fury of anyone with a proportional view of equity (i.e. anyone right-wing).
For a thoroughgoing analysis of these things from a famously left-leaning
economist, see Atkinson’s last book Inequality:
what can be done, especially chapter 3.
So to sum up, I broadly support this message, insofar as I correctly perceived that it is in Swan's speech: we need to strengthen, advance and
refine our market-disciplined welfare-state model to meet the challenges of a
very capital-friendly 21st century and ensure continued broad-based growth in Australia. But Wayne is way off on the
wrong-paddock when it comes to his technical analysis, and this makes me
worried about what kind of policies we are going to see championed by left-wing
parties over the next decade or two, especially as what I hear from the Labor right doesn't strike me as particularly switched on either (not to mention the Liberals and Torys).
Comments
Post a Comment