"Well-being” is increasingly advocated as a more appropriate target for shaping public policy than conventional economic metrics, and has attracted significant policy attention and advocacy. The adoption of well-being policies is attractive given the desirability of going ‘beyond GDP’ in order to assess progress. A range of wellbeing metrics based on large-scale surveys is increasingly available, enabling a large and growing body of empirical investigation. But some caution is needed before concluding that specific policies are the right ones to improve wellbeing.
One concern with this push to
implement wellbeing public policy (WPP) is that policymakers may start making
decisions impacting citizens’ lives based on ‘black box’ relationships. Numerous
commentators have noted that the subjective well-being (SWB)
literature in particular has (deliberately and for defensible reasons) taken an
empirical approach largely free of theory to studying relationships of
interest. This means that we lack, among other things, an understanding of the
mechanisms through which SWB interacts with many of the variables found in
empirical research to be correlated with it.
In other words, work on SWB policy
lacks knowledge of the pathways that reliably connects cause and effect. Such
an understanding is widely
thought to be necessary for evidence-based pursuits, be it
in medicine, care, or policy. Most of the headline findings in the SWB
literature, such as the u-shaped relationship between age and life
satisfaction, the Easterlin paradox, and adaptation, could potentially be
explained by multiple underlying drivers. So policy that takes no account of
this risks pulling the wrong lever, as it were, with unintended consequences.
For example, consider the extension
of ‘social prescribing’ to support people’s mental health or wellbeing in the
face of their complex needs. This involves linking patients in primary care to
sources of support within their community. There is no
systematic evidence of the efficacy of such programs, although there
are some long-established, well-regarded local schemes. The advocacy of social
prescribing seems to rest on atheoretical assumptions about a consistent
positive link between the various kinds of interventions that come under the
social prescribing rubric and wellbeing outcomes.
One theoretical
explanation for this observed link, from social psychology, is that group
membership is in itself a source of well-being. Other theories might justify
social prescription with different underlying drivers of wellbeing change, such
as self-expression through the arts, cortisol reductions from group exercise, reading
self-help books, the ‘eco-therapy’ of being in green space, or educational
opportunities.
If one of these underlying mechanisms
is responsible for wellbeing change then merely prescribing something social
will have little effect. What we need here is a theory of SWB that isolates its
different potential drivers so that precise hypotheses can be tested regarding
why a particular policy has an impact.
These concerns are relevant even
for the few causal claims currently made in the SWB policy literature, and for
lines of inquiry that take care to address simultaneity, or two-way
relationships. This is because the kind of empirical relationships captured in
the broad WPP literature are vulnerable to structural breaks known in the
context of macroeconomics as the Lucas critique, and also identified
in the more recent literature on the use of data science in
decision making.
Concisely, an estimated
relationship between SWB and some policy variable, like education, might depend
on the influence of many other variables, such as prevailing macroeconomic
conditions, geographic factors like local industries, social factors like
community infrastructure and culture, political and policy factors like tax and
transfer settings, and individual factors like personality type. A change in
any of these structural items may change the estimated relationship between
wellbeing and whatever covariate policymakers might target to improve it. A
theoretical understanding of wellbeing would help navigate the thicket of
possible influences and adjust policy accordingly.
We elaborate these arguments
concerning the need for more theory and mechanistic evidence in WPP in a new
working paper, available here.
We illustrate the way wellbeing data can be used to justify contrasting
policies, and argue for due caution in interpreting reduced form empirical
results in wellbeing, unless justified by a theory that imposes structure on
them. In the absence of theory, there is substantial risk of empirical results
pertaining to wellbeing lacking robustness, persistence, or generalizability.
Our argument that SWB theory
is not ready for policy complements recent analyses arguing that SWB measurement
is not ready for policy, and that more
ethical analysis needs to be done to bridge wellbeing science into
WPP. There is an important research agenda to develop and test theoretical
models of the determinants of well-being.
However, we want to stress that our
argument is not a counsel of perfection. Structural breaks are an unavoidable
feature of most social scientific analysis. Precise mechanistic analysis of
social phenomena is also notoriously difficult, and yet we seem to be able to
incrementally improve policy effectiveness. Central bankers, for example, seem
more in control today than during the great depression, despite the extreme
difficulty associated with experimental analysis of macroeconomics. Our
intention is simply to explain why caution is required with WPP at this
juncture and outline how future research could ameliorate that need to be
cautious.
Authors: Mark Fabian, Matthew Agarwala, Anna Alexandrova, Diane Coyle, Marco Felici
This blog was first published here, with the Bennett Institute for Public Policy.
Comments
Post a Comment